Arm’s Length Principle

Arm’s Length Principle

Arm’s Length Principle

Introduction to Arm’s Length Principle

The internationally recognized Arm’s Length Principle forms the basis of transfer pricing. It states that when related parties engage in transactions, the prices should be equivalent to those agreed upon in comparable transactions between unrelated parties. This principle is unanimously endorsed by OECD member countries and serves as a crucial guideline for multinational companies and tax administrations involved in international taxation.

While transactions between independent businesses are typically influenced by market forces, transactions between related businesses may not be directly influenced in the same way. Factors such as corporate synergies, economies of scale, or tax planning can affect the prices in related-party transactions. However, it is important not to automatically assume that related businesses are manipulating their profits. There can be genuine difficulties in determining a fair market price in the absence of market forces or when pursuing specific commercial strategies. Adjustments to approximate fair conditions according to the arm’s length principle may be necessary, regardless of contractual obligations or tax avoidance intentions.

When transfer pricing deviates from the arm’s length principle, it can lead to distorted tax liabilities for associated enterprises and tax revenues for host jurisdictions. To address these distortions, OECD member countries have agreed that adjustments may be made to the profits of associated enterprises for tax purposes. These adjustments aim to establish conditions in the commercial and financial relationships between associated enterprises that resemble those found between independent enterprises in comparable transactions.

Various factors can contribute to transfer pricing discrepancies. Related enterprises may face conflicting governmental pressures from domestic and foreign jurisdictions, such as customs valuations, anti-dumping duties, or exchange and price controls. Transfer price distortions can also arise due to the cash flow requirements of enterprises within multinational groups. Publicly held multinational groups may experience pressure from shareholders to demonstrate high profitability at the parent company level, particularly if consolidated shareholder reporting is not undertaken. These factors can influence transfer prices and the allocation of profits within multinational enterprises. It is important to recognize that factors other than tax considerations can also distort the conditions of commercial and financial relationships.

For example, local managers within MNEs have a vested interest in achieving favorable profit outcomes, leading them to set prices that protect their own companies’ profitability. Tax administrations should consider these factors to effectively allocate their resources when selecting and conducting transfer pricing examinations. It is crucial to recognize that the nature of the relationship between associated enterprises can influence the bargaining process. Therefore, simply demonstrating intense negotiations alone does not establish that the transactions are conducted in accordance with the arm’s length principle.

Arm’s Length Principle in the OECD Model

The arm’s length principle, articulated in paragraph I of Article 9 of the OECD Model Tax Convention (click here to read: https://www.oecd.org/tax/treaties/1914467.pdf ), serves as the authoritative guideline for transfer pricing. It establishes the framework for bilateral tax treaties involving OECD member countries and an expanding number of non-member countries. According to Article 9, when the terms and conditions governing the commercial and financial relationships between associated enterprises deviate from those observed in transactions between independent entities, any unrealized profits arising from these deviations can be attributed to the respective enterprise and subject to taxation.

The fundamental objective of the arm’s length principle is to align profits with the conditions prevailing in comparable transactions conducted between independent entities, commonly referred to as “comparable uncontrolled transactions”. By treating members of a multinational enterprise (MNE) group as distinct entities rather than integral parts of a unified enterprise, this principle places significant emphasis on scrutinizing the transactions between these entities to ascertain whether the terms and conditions differ from those found in comparable uncontrolled transactions. This critical assessment, known as a “comparability analysis”, lies at the very essence of applying the arm’s length principle.

To achieve a balance between reliability and the impact on taxpayers and tax administrations, it is essential to provide context for the issue of comparability. The fundamental basis for conducting comparability analyses is found in paragraph I of Article 9 of the OECD Model Tax Convention. 

The comparison of conditions, including not only prices but also other relevant factors, imposed or agreed upon between associated enterprises, with those that would be present between independent enterprises. This comparison aims to determine if an adjustment to the financial records, for the purpose of calculating the tax liabilities of associated enterprises, is justified under Article 9 of the OECD Model Tax Convention.

Pros of the Arm’s Length Principle

OECD member countries and other jurisdictions have embraced the arm’s length principle for several compelling reasons. One of the primary rationales is that it ensures a fair and equitable tax treatment between multinational enterprise (MNE) groups and independent enterprises. By placing associated and independent entities on a more equal footing for tax purposes, the arm’s length principle prevents the creation of tax advantages or disadvantages that could distort their relative competitive positions. Consequently, the principle removes tax considerations from economic decisions and fosters the growth of international trade and investment.

In the majority of cases, the arm’s length principle can be applied effectively. Transactions involving the purchase and sale of commodities, money lending, and financial indicators such as mark-up on costs, gross margin, or net profit often allow for straightforward comparison with comparable transactions between independent enterprises under similar circumstances. However, there are notable cases where the application of the arm’s length principle becomes challenging and complex. These include MNE groups engaged in the integrated production of highly specialized goods, unique intangibles, or the provision of specialized services. Nevertheless, solutions exist to address such difficult cases, including the utilization of the transactional profit split method outlined in Chapter II, Part III of the Guidelines when it is deemed the most suitable method given the specific circumstances of the case.

Cons of the Arm’s Length Principle

 The arm’s length principle is subject to criticism as some argue that it may have inherent flaws due to the limitations of the separate entity approach. This approach may not always adequately consider the economies of scale and interrelationships inherent in integrated businesses. Additionally, there is a lack of widely accepted objective criteria for allocating economies of scale and integration benefits among associated enterprises within a group.

One practical challenge in applying the arm’s length principle arises when associated enterprises engage in transactions that independent enterprises would not typically undertake. These transactions may not be driven by tax avoidance but rather by the different commercial circumstances faced by members of a the MNE group when transacting with each other. In cases where independent enterprises rarely engage in similar transactions, applying the arm’s length principle becomes difficult because there is limited or no direct evidence regarding the conditions that independent enterprises would have established. It is important to note that the absence of a transaction between independent parties does not automatically imply that the transaction is not at arm’s length.

The application of the arm’s length principle can pose administrative challenges for taxpayers and tax administrations, particularly when dealing with a significant volume and diverse range of cross-border transactions. While associated enterprises typically determine the transaction conditions at the time of execution, they may later be required to demonstrate compliance with the arm’s length principle. This verification process, which can occur years after the transactions, involves the tax administration reviewing the taxpayer’s supporting documentation and gathering information on comparable uncontrolled transactions and market conditions. As time passes, this task becomes more complex.

Obtaining adequate information to apply the arm’s length principle is a common challenge faced by both tax administrations and taxpayers. The principle entails evaluating uncontrolled transactions and the business activities of independent enterprises, and comparing them to those of associated enterprises. This process demands a substantial amount of data, which can be incomplete and difficult to interpret. Moreover, geographical limitations or confidentiality concerns can hinder access to relevant information. In some cases, there may be a lack of comparable independent enterprises, especially in highly vertically integrated industries. Nonetheless, the goal remains to reasonably estimate an arm’s length outcome based on reliable information. It is essential to recognize that transfer pricing is not a precise science, but rather requires the exercise of judgment from both the tax administration and the taxpayer.

For more information about transfer pricing and the arm’s length principle click here.

Contact Us

Recent Articles​

Popular Articles

Consult A Tax Expert